Idiots savants, αδειάστε μας την γωνιά!

Η Δευτέρα που μας πέρασε ήταν μια μεγάλη μέρα κατά την γνώμη μου για το επάγγελμα των οικονομολόγων και την οικονομική επιστήμη γενικότερα. Το βραβείο Nobel πήγε στον Oliver Williamson του UC Berkeley και την Elinor Ostrom του Indiana University (και του Arizona State University, μην πέσει το σπίτι και μας πλακώσει). Εστιάζω εδώ περισσότερο στην Ostrom, η οποία φάνηκε σχετικά άγνωστη στους κύκλους των οικονομολόγων – τουλάχιστον σε κύκλους που μάλλον πρέπει να αρχίσουν να διαβάζουν περισσότερα βιβλία κατά τη γνώμη μου. Ακόμα πιο τραγικό ήταν πως αρκετοί οικονομολόγοι δεν γνώριζαν επίσης και την δουλειά του Williamson… Την πορεία τους περιγράφει καλά ο David Henderson στην WSJ:

Yesterday’s award of the Nobel Prize in economics to Elinor Ostrom and Oliver Williamson at first struck me as a good choice. Now I think it’s a great choice. The reason is that mainstream economics has become highly mathematical and increasingly independent from reality. Many economists sit in their offices and derive proofs. Few go out and do the time-consuming work of examining the institutional structures that humans build to solve their own real-world problems. Among those few are Ms. Ostrom and Mr. Williamson.
Both draw on rich data from outside the field of economics. Ms. Ostrom draws much of hers from case studies of common-property resources and Mr. Williamson from business historians such as the late Alfred Chandler. Some have summarized their work by saying that institutions other than free markets often work well. But that statement can mislead you to conclude that government solutions are the answer. Free markets are only a subset of free institutions. A better way to sum up their work is that what Ms. Ostrom and Mr. Willamson really show is that voluntary associations work.
[…]
How about Ms. Ostrom’s work? Most economists are familiar with the late Garrett Hardin’s classic article, “The Tragedy of the Commons.” His idea was that when no one owns a resource, it is overused because no one can control its usage and each person has an incentive to use it before others do. This insight has helped us understand much human behavior and has led people to advocate either having the resource privately owned or having it controlled by government.
Not so fast, said Ms. Ostrom. Examining dozens of case studies, she found cases of communal ownership that worked—that is, that didn’t lead to the tragic outcomes envisioned by Hardin—as well as ones that didn’t. Were there systematic differences? Yes, and interestingly the ones that worked did have a kind of property rights system, just not private ownership.
Based on her work, Ms. Ostrom proposed several rules for managing common-pool resources, which the Nobel committee highlights. Among them are that rules should clearly define who gets what, good conflict resolution methods should be in place, people’s duty to maintain the resource should be proportional to their benefits, monitoring and punishing is done by the users or someone accountable to the users, and users are allowed to participate in setting and modifying the rules. Notice the absence of top-down government solutions. In her work on development economics, Ms. Ostrom concludes that top-down solutions don’t help poor countries. Are you listening, World Bank?
In a 2006 article with Harini Nagendra, Ms. Ostrom wrote: “We conclude that simple formulas focusing on formal ownership, particularly one based solely on public [government] ownership of forest lands, will not solve the problem of resource use.” Garth Owen-Smith, who helped solve the common-resource problem of elephants in Namibia by ensuring that local residents shared in the financial benefits from tourism and trophy hunting, drew explicitly on Ms. Ostrom’s work. If locals benefit from having a resident population of elephants, they are much less likely to poach and more likely to stop other poachers.
Economists talking about real humans and not mathematical abstractions and winning the Nobel prize for it? Good on ya, Nobel committee.

Η δουλειά της Ostrom (μια καλή επιστημονική περίληψη θα βρείτε εδώ) είναι κατά βάση εμπειρική και εξετάζει προβλήματα συλλογικών αγαθών. Έχει δείξει πως η ιστορία της “τραγωδίας των κοινών” (η περίπτωση που μια ομάδα ατόμων που κινείται με βάση το προσωπικό συμφέρον και με αυτόνομη οργάνωση καταλήγει να εξαφανίζει κοινούς περιορισμένους πόρους ενώ τα μέλη της ομάδας κατανοούν πως μακροχρόνια η συμπεριφορά που επιδεικνύουν δεν είναι προς όφελός τους) δεν είναι αναγκαστικά η εικόνα της κατάστασης που συνήθως επικρατεί παγκοσμίως. Δείχνει επίσης πως προβλήματα βιώσιμης χρήσης κοινών πόρων είναι σε πολλές περιπτώσεις επιλύσιμα υπό το κατάλληλο θεσμικό καθεστώς – που προϋποθέτει χρήση ποικιλίας θεσμών.

Read moreIdiots savants, αδειάστε μας την γωνιά!

Economics Nobel 2007: Playing games and designing mechanisms

At last. Mechanism designers got their Nobel prize. But did they deserve it?

For me economics became a science sometime around 1945* with John von Neumann’s and Oskar Morgenstern’s Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Naturally, this book was only an outline of things to come and far from finishing the edifice we call today game theory. It took the subsequent efforts of people like John Nash, John Harsanyi, Reinhard Selten, Robert Aumann and Thomas Schelling to complete this beautiful structure of clear rationality expressed through elegant mathematical formulation.

The first Nobel prizes however for the masters of this field came only in 1994 (Harsanyi, Nash, Selten). Maybe it is the traditional reluctance of the Swedes to acknowledge the importance of new fields, or other reasons, it does not matter. But it seems that since 1994 they are trying to correct their mistake by awarding prizes to all the other aforementioned researchers and also people who I consider to be related to GT like William Vickrey, Vernon Smith etc.

It seems microeconomics and especially game theory are accepted now as one of the strongest tools in the social sciences with applications from biology to sociology. Mechanism design is one of these applications and it was chosen to be honoured this year, with the Nobel prize going to Leonid Hurwicz, Eric S. Maskin and Roger B. Myerson “for having laid the foundations of mechanism design theory”.

Mechanism what?
So what is mechanism design and was this honour warranted?

Read moreEconomics Nobel 2007: Playing games and designing mechanisms